Externalities, contagious diseases and news

From Wikiversity
Jump to navigation Jump to search
This essay is on Wikiversity to encourage a wide discussion of the issues it raises moderated by the Wikimedia rules that invite contributors to “be bold but not reckless,” contributing revisions written from a neutral point of view, citing credible sources, and raising other questions and concerns on the associated '“Discuss”' page.

Abstract[edit | edit source]

This article discusses positive externalities and anti-rivalry, focusing on two examples: (a) Anything that could help control a contagious disease,[1] and (b) News, especially regarding political corruption or anything else that could improve the productivity of the economy. A good has positive externalities if consumption by one benefits others. A good is anti-rivalrous if consumption by one makes it easier for another to consume it. For public health the economic question is to design public policy to minimize the present value of the disease burden in perpetuity at some reasonable discount rate. This suggests that the price to the consumer of a test, treatment, vaccine or other risk-reduction protocol for a contagious disease should be the maximum of (a) the marginal cost of producing an additional unit minus the benefit to others and (b) the minimum charge required to appropriately limit waste. Any patent royalties should be paid by taxpayers and should not be considered in the price to the consumer. Secondly, anyone who travels should be required to carry liability insurance to cover the losses suffered by others directly or indirectly infected from them. Consider smallpox eradication: In 1967 the global disease burden was estimated at $1.35 billion (USD) annually. The eradication effort cost a total of $300 million spread over 1967 to 1979. The US was the largest contributor to that eradication effort and has reportedly recouped its investment every 26 days since.[2] For many other goods that improve public health, like diagnostic procedures to name only one, the marginal cost of an additional unit may be so low and the benefits so large that any group of countries representing some modest portion of the gross world product would be healthier and wealthier if they paid for the entire world. News also has positive externalities: If someone in power believes I may disseminate information on political corruption involving them, I could be killed like Jamal Khashoggi. I'm much healthier and wealthier if everyone else knows about that political corruption, because it's more likely to be fixed, whether I'm aware of it or not. Also, an obstacle to improving public health is that much of the money for many media organizations in the US comes from patent royalties, which gives the US media a conflict of interest in honestly discussing these issues.[3]

Introduction[edit | edit source]

Laurie Garrett (2000) wrote that public health is "a practical system ... rooted in two fundamental scientific tenets: the germ theory of disease and the understanding that preventing disease in the weakest elements of society ensured protection for the strongest (and richest)".[4] She also reported that, "Vital statistics data from England, Wales, and Sweden show that in 1700 the average male lived just twenty-seven to thirty years. By 1971 male life expectancy reached seventy-five years. ... [In] the United States ... less than 4 percent of the total improvement in life expectancy since the 1700s can be attributed to twentieth century advances in medical care. It is a matter of considerable academic debate which factors were most responsible for the spectacular improvements in life expectancy and infant mortality seen in the United States and Western Europe between 1700 and 1900." Factors mentioned include improved sewers, clean water, education and government responses to epidemics.[5] Even when direct access to improved sewers, clean water, education and government responses to epidemics is not universal, people who do not have such access may still benefit when diseases circulate less and other goods and services become easier to obtain. When that happens, the better sewers, water, education, and government response to epidemics carry positive externalities. But most of the innovations that contributed to those improvements in life expectancy "would have died in the cradle but for persuaders and activists who championed the innovation and policies", according to Pinker and Johnson.[6] The dissemination of information that motivated those persuaders and activists carried huge positive externalities, benefitting people who may never have lifted a finger to obtain the improvements in health they enjoy as a result.

The present article starts by discussing positive externalities and the concept of rivalry in economics, including non-rivalry, and anti-rivalry. We then discuss how these concepts apply to news, especially about political corruption and research. The positive externalities from the eradication of a disease like smallpox can be enormous, benefitting every human living after the eradication. Public health systems for testing, diagnosing, tracking, treating, vaccinating for and limiting the transmission of infectious diseases also carry huge positive externalities, as explained herein.

Externalities, Rivalry, non-rivalry, anti-rivalry[edit | edit source]

This section briefly reviews the concepts of externalities and rivalry in economics.

In economics, an externality is a cost or benefit for a third party who did not agree to it. Pollution is a negative externality.

A good in economics is called rivalrous if consumption by one precludes consumption by another. A standard example is an apple: If I eat one, you cannot eat the same one. We must produce another -- or split one, so we each eat different parts of the same apple. (In this article, we use the term "good" to include a service. For example, a haircut is rivalrous, because if I give you a haircut, I cannot give someone else the same haircut.)

Similarly a good is called non-rivalrous if consumption by one has no impact on the ability of another to consume the same good. An example is a radio or television broadcast: The consumption by one has no impact on the ability of another to consume the same broadcast.

There seems not to have been as much research on anti-rivalry, but it seems reasonable to say that a good is anti-rivalrous if consumption by one makes it easier for others to consume it. This allows us to think of rivalry as a continuum from competition to collaboration: We compete to obtain rivalrous goods. We collaborate with anti-rivalrous goods.

Languages are anti-rivalrous: When more people use a particular language, they develop more literature in that language, thereby making it easier to learn. Free and open-source software is similarly anti-rivalrous.[7]

Nikander et al. claim that data may be anti-rivalrous.[8] However, that may not be true if governments and major organizations use data secretly to harm their designated enemies and threaten democracy.[9]

Efforts to combat climate change are reportedly perversely anti-rivalrous, because the countries that do not support the international efforts to combat this problem will continue to benefit from what others do without making any efforts to change themselves,[10] unless other countries impose global warming Pigovian taxes on trade with countries that refuse to support international efforts to manage this problem.[11]

Rivalry and externalities
Externalities
Negative Negligible Positive
Rivalrous goods whose production or consumption pollutes the environment, e.g., fossil fuels; printed literature that is racist or inciting inappropriate violence Organic food; printed literature that is entertaining Vaccinations; printed literature that disseminates information on political corruption or technology for how to more easily produce goods with positive externalities.
Non-rivalrous Spyware; computer viruses; broadcasts advocating racism and inciting inappropriate violence, e.g., Father Coughlin's radio broadcasts in the late 1930s and very early 1940s Entertainment broadcasted or on the Internet (unless it helps people learn a language, in which case it's anti-rivalrous) Broadcasts or web sites the distribute news that might help limit political corruption or help people learn how to more efficiently produce more goods with positive externalities.
Anti-rivalrous Literature that is racist or inciting inappropriate violence that is freely available on the Internet that helps people learn a language or understand these alternative perspectives, e.g., Henry Ford's International Jew, Adolf Hitler's Mein Kampf. Entertainment that is broadcasted or is free on the Internet that helps people learn a language. (NOTE: Such literature has some positive externalities but not as much as news and information on how to produce goods with positive externalities.) Freely available historical literature that was used in the past to limit political corruption or promote public health or make people more productive; Free and open-source software (FOSS).

News about political corruption[edit | edit source]

News about political corruption is anti-rivalrous with positive externalities, because increased awareness of the details often leads to action reversing widely condemned cases while encouraging institutional reforms making similar instances of political corruption less frequent and costly in the future. When that happens, everyone benefits from the resulting positive externalities. Moreover the benefits are shared among people who did nothing to encourage reforms, making the access easily obtained, i.e., making the news that motivated such reforms anti-rivalrous.[12]

McChesney and Nichols argued that the dominant position of the United State in today's international political economy is built in part on the US Postal Service Act of 1792. Under that act, newspapers were delivered up to 100 miles for a penny when first class postage was between 6 and 25 cents. That amounted to roughly 0.2 percent of national income (Gross Domestic Product, GDP), which corresponded to roughly $100 per person per year in 2012.[13] Many if not all humans alive in the US today benefit from the improvements in literacy and limits on political corruption encouraged by nineteenth-century US newspapers: This provides positive externalities that are anti-rivalrous, because people in the US today benefit from the consumption by others in the nineteenth century without ever having accessed those newspapers themselves.

Benson and Powers (2011) surveyed the media in fifteen advanced industrialized democracies. Each had a mix of public and private media. They claimed that the public media tended to provide better coverage of news and public affairs than the commercial media, primarily because the public media had better firewalls that more effectively limited interference in the content by funders. Most had multi-year funding with oversight boards with only limited input from the current government in power. The US was the exception, whose per capita public spending is less than $4, far less than the $30 to $134 per capita for the other 14 countries examined in this study. Moreover funding for public broadcasting in the US is renewed every year, which made it the most susceptible to political interference in the content.

Figure 1. Life expectancy in selected countries and regions since 1950. w = World. la = Latin America and the Caribbean. jp = Japan. cu = Cuba. ee = Eastern Europe. ne = Northern Europe. se = Southern Europe. we = Western Europe. ca = Canada. us = United States of America (Table e0, both sexes, in "Mortality data" in World Population Prospects, United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Wikidata Q41274869, 2019).

Research publications[edit | edit source]

Publications advancing technology, especially regarding human health, are anti-rivalrous: Documents disseminating previous innovations in public health and health care have contributed to reducing the risks of disease and death for the vast majority of the world's population documented in Figures 1 and 2: People who have never read those documents live longer on average today because others inspired by those research reports took actions that benefitted many others.

Figure 2. Infant mortality in selected countries and regions since 1950. Legend as with Figure 1. (IMR table in Mortality data in World Population Prospects, United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Wikidata Q41274869, 2019).

News and public health[edit | edit source]

The lines for Eastern Europe in Figures 1 and 2 show much slower progress in public health than the rest of the world. One possible explanation for this is that the press there has been more tightly controlled than in the rest of the world.

Figure 3. Percent correct answers in surveys of knowledge of domestic and international politics vs. per capita subsidies for public media in the Denmark (DK), Finland (FI), the United Kingdom (UK) and the United States (US). Source: The "politicalKnowledge" data set in the "Ecdat" package available on the Comprehensive R Archive Network, based on research cited by McChesney and Nichols (2010).

Similarly, it is striking that the US has lost the position it held in 1950 as one of the world leaders in life expectancy and infant mortality. Since then, Northern, Western, and Southern Europe along with Canada and Japan have improved faster. The slower rate of improvement in the US might be explained by differences in how the media in different countries are funded and governed.[14]

Every media organization sells changes in audience behaviors to their funders, people who give them money. They all therefore have conflicts of interest in disseminating information that might offend a major funder.[3] Benson and Powers (2011), mentioned above, note that the US has the weakest firewall between funding and content of any of the 15 advanced industrialized countries they studied. This means that media organizations in the US funded primarily by advertising must be more careful to avoid offending big pharma or the health insurance industry than their counterparts in other developed countries.

This difference could also explain the results displayed in Figure 3, that people without college degrees tend to be less well informed in the US than in the UK and Scandinavia.

The extent to which news can be anti-rivalrous is limited by constraints on funding. This suggests that the most anti-rivalrous funding structure may be something like that provided by the US Postal Service Act of 1792, mentioned above. Prior to the US Civil War, newspapers accepted advertising, but most of their funding came from readers, some directly, most indirectly in the form of the postal subsidies. After the US Civil War, advertising gradually became the primary source of funding for news in the US.[15] To the extent that the improvements in public health documented in Figures 1 and 2 should be attributed to the media, this suggests that since World War II US media may have been more constrained than in other advanced industrialized countries that have more institutional restraints on political interference in editorial policies. (In the US, the reliance on advertising from major corporations limits media editorial independence, especially given the near elimination of investigative journalists by the major US broadcasters between 1975 and 2000 and the loss of 70 percent of advertising revenue by US newspapers since 2004, which led to a 50 percent reduction in newspaper journalists and the closure of a quarter of US newspapers.[16])[3]

The quality of healthcare in Cuba is a contentious issue. People on the political left claim that the Cuban healthcare system is a model for the entire world, but others insist that data from a closed society like Communist Cuba are not to be trusted.[17] However, if Garrett (2000, p. 10), cited above, is correct, no country need twenty-first century medicine to achieve life expectancy and infant mortality numbers like those in Figures 1 and 2: They only need to provide things like adequate nutrition, good sewers, and clean water to the poorest elements of society. To the extent that good sewers and water reduce the total disease burden of society, they are anti-rivalrous, because I'm unlikely to catch a contagious disease that few others have.

Pricing anti-rivalrous goods[edit | edit source]

Public policy should minimize the present value of the disease burden in perpetuity at some reasonable discount rate. The optimal price to the consumer of a vaccine is often zero for two reasons: First, the benefits to everyone else (positive externalities) exceed the marginal cost of an additional unit of vaccine. Second, a negative price could mean paying people to get vaccinated, and that could create an industry of poor people being vaccinated multiple times. For most goods, reducing the price usually increases the demand. For anti-rivalrous goods, increasing the demand benefits society, even if the price to the consumer is less than the marginal cost of producing and distributing the good. For many such goods, the optimal price is zero.

A positive price for anti-rivalrous goods may be justified if they also have uses that are not anti-rivalrous like N95 respirators. The general rule is that you and I should be willing to subsidize consumption of goods by others whenever said consumption benefits us. With goods with multiple uses only some of which are anti-rivalrous, we'd ideally like to subsidize only those uses that have positive externalities. However, with some goods it may not be economically feasible to subsidize only some uses.

A mathematical framework for modeling both the benefits and the costs of producing and distributing such goods is outlined in a mathematical appendix at the end of this article. In this framework, any patent and copyright royalties should be combined with the fixed costs: Otherwise, they discourage uses that would benefit others.[18]

With disease eradication programs, the benefits can potentially be huge. As discussed in the next section, everyone alive today pays nothing for the benefits they derive from the smallpox eradication program, which officially ended in 1979. We then consider other contagious diseases, then disease monitoring both for future previously unknown diseases like COVID was in mid-2020 and for sexually transmitted infections (STIs), then for face masks. We then briefly discuss requiring travelers to carry liability insurance for contagious diseases they may transmit with rates adjusted based on the available data on the documented effectiveness of the vaccines they've taken.

Smallpox[edit | edit source]

One example of incredible anti-rivalry is the smallpox eradication program of the 1960s and 1970s. In the late 1960s the disease burden of smallpox was estimated at between 10 and 15 million cases costing roughly $1.35 billion (USD) annually in the losses from sickness and death plus the cost of vaccinating people. The eradication campaign spent roughly $23 million for each of the 13 years between 1967 and 1979 totalling $300 million. International donors provided $98 million, while $200 million came from the endemic countries.[2][19]

The documentation I've seen of the smallpox eradication program does not mention any fee charged to those who were vaccinated, but it was presumably either zero or so low that the price was not a consideration for any of those vaccinated, especially in the latter stages of the campaign. If the price had been higher, fewer people would likely have been vaccinated when they did, which likely would have extended the duration and increased the total cost of the program. And they presumably did not pay people to get vaccinated, which could have generated a small industry of poor people getting vaccinated repeatedly for the money.

One important aspect of this for the present discussion is that everyone alive today benefits from that $300 million program that ended in 1979. We are not even asked to pay a penny for the benefits (positive externalities) we derive from that program. Some of us would not even be here. Some of us born before 1979 would have died from smallpox without it. Others born more recently not have been born, because one of their parents or grandparents would have died before they were conceived. The rest of us would have a shorter life expectancy and higher cost of health care, because of the cost of vaccinating and otherwise managing smallpox that were eliminated, presumably in perpetuity, by that program.

Similarly, any consortium of countries experiencing, e.g., 10 percent of that total annual cost of $1.35 billion could have paid the entire $300 million and gotten their money back every 2.22 years (= $300 million divided by 10 percent of $1.35 billion) in perpetuity. The United States, the largest contributor to the program, has reportedly recouped its investment every 26 days since in money not spent on (a) vaccinations and (b) the costs of incidence. If the US had paid the entire $300 million, they still would be getting an incredible return on that investment, ignoring the benefits to the rest of humanity.

Other contagious diseases[edit | edit source]

A 2001 analysis of what the United States saves through standard childhood vaccinations estimated that, after the costs to deliver the vaccines, and the health care costs for the rare side effects that vaccines cause, society saves nearly $10 billion in direct medical costs, and $47 billion in indirect costs like lost worker productivity and permanent disability from disease; this was the total life cycle cost for all the children born in 2001 discounted at 3 percent.[20] The US Gross Domestic Product in 2001 was $10.6 trillion with a population of 285 million.[21] Thus, the dollar value of the anti-rivalry, positive externalities, of childhood vaccinates is roughly 0.5 percent of GDP ($57 / $10,600) and $200 per person ($57,000 / 285), not counting the increased costs to public health systems due to an epidemic or pandemic.

Other eradication programs are targeting polio, dracunculiasis (Guinea worm), yaws (caused by a spirochete similar to syphilis) and malaria. Obstacles to eradication include the need to (a) upgrade public health systems in poor countries to avoid diverting the few trained health workers from concerns that seem more pressing, and (b) guard against "reintroduction from areas where poverty, civil unrest, or lack of political will impede high vaccination coverage and sustain endemicity."[2]

Western military activities and support for corrupt regimes in Muslim countries on top of the legacy of colonial domination have reportedly contributed to boycotts of the polio vaccine and spikes in cases in Afghanistan, Pakistan,[22] Nigeria,[23] Kenya,[24] and elsewhere. An honest budget for the War in Afghanistan (2001–present) should include the negative externalities from the increased burden of disease in the US and its allies, whose military operations in Afghanistan and other support for political corruption in Muslim countries are reflected in the resistance to vaccination efforts.

Those obstacles to eradication seem likely to result from a general absence of quality news required to build a consensus for action against threats experienced by all, similar to the discussion with Figures 1 and 2 above that attributed limited progress in public health in Eastern Europe and the US to conflicts of interest in the mainstream media on those countries.

The anti-rivalrous nature of vaccines is implied by the concept of herd immunity: If everyone with whom I interact is vaccinated, I'm not likely to get a disease, even if I have not been vaccinated. Other public health measures like diagnostic testing and masks can be similarly anti-rivalrous.

Disease testing[edit | edit source]

One of the major obstacles to managing COVID-19 has been the availability of tests, especially early in the pandemic. Before entering a retail outlet in the US in March 2021, a store employee took my temperature with a forehead scanner. I asked what it was: 70 °F (21 °C). That's Stage 3 hypothermia: I would have been unconscious or dead, not on my feet, trying to enter a retail outlet with that body temperature.

But a forehead fever thermometer is anti-rivalrous, because it reduces the risk of people being exposed to a disease when shopping -- and it would be even better if it were reasonably accurate![25]

Diagnostic procedures with less error usually (a) make it easier to identify and manage contagious individuals and (b) increase the value of contact tracing. Both of these tend to reduce the spread of the condition. In addition more accurate diagnostics make it easier to development vaccines, treatment modalities, and other procedures for managing the spread of a disease. When a person with a contagious condition is diagnosed, steps are usually taken to reduce the number of others who would likely catch that disease.

Even if an outbreak occurs on the other side of the planet, more accurate diagnosis and better control limits the spread and with it the chances that I will catch that disease. Better control also on average reduces disruptions to the economy from people not producing as much when sick. If the disruptions are large enough, they can reduce the availability of seemingly unrelated products (like toilet paper in the US early in the COVID-19 pandemic) and the cost of obtaining such. These positive externalities indicate that I would benefit from subsidizing the use of any such test procedure any place in the world if my subsidies sufficiently increased the use of better diagnostic procedures.

Some contagious diseases could be eradicated if anyone who didn't feel well had convenient access to a sufficiently accurate test. Such tests could help diagnose their condition and prescribe actions to maximize their rate of recovery while minimizing the chances of infecting others. This may not work if many people who are contagious are asymptomatic unless they are subjected to effective routine screening, e.g., when entering some public space like public transit, retail or office space.

There are in fact several research strains moving in this direction. Harvard Chemistry professor Whitesides predicts "Zero cost diagnostics" for almost any medical condition in the not-too-distant future.[26] These predictions are based on rates of improvement comparable to Moore's law, which has described the doubling of the number of transistors in a microprocessor almost every two years since 1970; it is named after Gordon Moore, co-founder of Fairchild Semiconductor and Intel, who first predicted something like this in 1965.

Moore's law is a special case of experience curve effects, which is an empirical observation that each time the cumulative production of almost anything doubles, the unit cost drops by roughly a constant percentage, with the rate of improvement varying between products and industries. While it's not clear what determines this rate of improvement, it is clear that providing more money to fund research by competent experts tends to increase the rate of progress. Both the Salk and Sabin polio vaccines were funded by the March of Dimes, founded in 1938 as the National Foundation for Infantile Paralysis by Franklin D. Roosevelt, himself a polio victim and president of the US at that time. Twenty years later, two different vaccines were being administered worldwide and have since come close to eradicating polio.

Whitesides has proposed developing specially treated paper for low-cost diagnosis of health problems, analogous to litmus paper, which has been used for roughly 700 years to test acidity. Others are developing "lab-on-a-chip" devices. Both types of products hold the promise of rapid, low cost diagnosis of almost anything, including DNA sequencing of previously unknown pathogens for pennies. The genome for a single human could be sequenced in 2020 for $600, down from over $3 billion the first time it was done (1990-2003). A $100 genome is anticipated "soon"; a $10 genome is reportedly not far away. Harvard geneticist George Church predicated "one day sensors might 'sip the air' so that a genomic app on our phones can tell us if there’s a pathogen lurking in a room." The human genome has 3 billion letters but SARS-CoV-2 has only about 30,000 letters. This makes it much easier and cheaper to sequence something like a SARS-CoV-2 sample than the genome from an individual human. The widespread availability of relatively inexpensive sequencing has allowed researchers to monitor the evolution of SARS-CoV-2 essentially in real time.[27]

Joseph DeRisi has developed a system called "IDseq" for "metagenomics", whose goal is to inventory all the viruses and living organisms in a sample of almost anything, e.g., bodily fluids or sewage. It does this by matching overlapping fragments of nucleotide sequences in the sample. The assembled genomes are then compared against a database of all the known sequences maintained by the National Center for Biotechnology Information (NCBI), part of the US government, to identify all known and previously unknown viruses and living organisms in the sample. This system has made major contributions to understanding many different diseases all over the world, including COVID.[28]

The global burden from influenza might be dramatically reduced through low cost testing of domestic pigs and fowl. Aquatic birds are reportedly the primary reservoir of the influenza A virus, which is responsible for most cases of severe illness, epidemics and pandemics in humans. Influenza also circulates among mammals, especially pigs, which have often facilitated the transmission to humans.[29]

Major obstacles to progress are sufficiently widespread understanding of (a) the benefits of research and (b) effective and efficient ways of managing research to benefit all.

A goal simpler than the universal diagnosis just mentioned might be reasonable diagnostics for known sexually transmitted infection (STI): We'd need something that could test for these conditions crudely like testing blood oxygen level or using saliva or some other body fluid, e.g., a drop of blood like a glucose test. If anyone could do it discreetly in the presence of a potential partner, that could become standard practice worldwide: When one partner tested positive, they might still engage in intimate behaviour that was not high risk.

Roughly 16 percent of the world population of 7.4 billion had a sexually transmitted infection other than HIV/AIDS in 2015.[30] It may be worse in the US. A 2008 study by the US Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) reported that a quarter of US teenage girls have at least one of four infections monitored in the study.[31]

Even people who are 100 percent monogamous would benefit from widely used and accurate test(s) for common STIs. Some partners are clandestinely unfaithful. Moreover, widespread use of such testing would reduce the likelihood that rape spreads STIs. This makes such testing substantively anti-rivalrous.

Public health monitoring[edit | edit source]

Public health programs are anti-rivalrous, benefitting even people who are unaware of them. In December 2019, before anyone outside of China had heard of COVID-19, Charity Dean saw there was a major problem from her monitoring of internet traffic for key words. Dean was the number 2 public health official in California but was unable to convince her manager that there was a problem. Instead, her manager excluded her from key meetings, apparently believing that Dean's claims were a waste of her time. Eventually a couple of Silicon Valley executives got Dean's message through to Governor Newsom, who issued a stay-home order -- after COVID-19 was already a major problem in California.[32] In 2020-09-28 O'Leary and Storey described how they could predict "the number of people in the USA who will become infected and die from the coronavirus" using "the number of Google searches, Twitter tweets, and Wikipedia page views".[33] In fact this is a cheap way to monitor for all kinds of problems including emerging and evolving conflicts, natural disasters, and public health crises.

Public health officials in the US announced in August 2020[34] that they were creating a new tool called the "National Wastewater Surveillance System (NWSS)" that would "include a portal for state, tribal, local, and territorial health departments to share wastewater testing data, helping public health officials better understand community spread" of conditions like COVID-19. For that in particular, they are asking wastewater treatment facilities to test "sewage for RNA from SARS-CoV-2". With this they can model which strains are active where as well as the emergence of new strains.[35]

The development in recent decades of electronic health records provide the promise of computer-assisted health care monitoring, suggesting additional tests and alternative therapies. They could also be used for public health monitoring and research. Unfortunately, there is a sad record of use by people in business and government to track and punish their perceived enemies. This has been countered in the past by an emphasis on privacy, protected in the US by the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act (HIPAA).

However, is Ed Snowden in Russia to avoid prosecution for exposing violations of US law by public officials? If that seems plausible, it suggests a need to change US law to make it harder for public officials to hide possible criminal activities, especially ones that the public would likely not support, with questionable claims of national security. Graves (2014) suggested we give every federal judge the authority to subpoena classified documents that may be relevant to a case in their jurisdiction and declassify them in whole or part if the judge believes the public interest is better served by openness, subject to appellate review of any declassification ruling. Currently, per the US Supreme Court decision in United States v. Reynolds (1953), no federal judge can question a claim of national security by a government official. Changing US law to overrule US v. Reynolds would have anti-rivalrous effects, including encouraging more complete and honest evaluation of questionable interference in foreign countries, like the killing of Osama bin Laden and four others of his household, without benefit of trial by jury, in a way that has had many other negative externalities, including slowing progress to the eradication of polio, mentioned earlier.

Face masks[edit | edit source]

Face masks provide an interesting example of a product that can be used to limit the spread of contagious diseases. How should they be priced? The general rule for pricing mentioned above is the minimum of (a) the marginal cost of production minus the benefit to society and (b) a minimum charge required to limit waste. In this case, "waste" could include otherwise legitimate use in applications like painting or working in a dusty environment, which are not anti-rivalrous. The public should not be expected to pay patent royalties for uses that are not anti-rivalrous. For an outline of mathematical modeling for such applications, see the mathematical appendix at the end of this article.

Vaccine hesitancy and liability insurance for contagious diseases[edit | edit source]

Ropeik said, "A 2008 study in Michigan found that areas with “exemption clusters” where more parents chose not to have their kids vaccinated were three times more likely to have outbreaks of pertussis than where vaccination rates matched the state average.[36] ... A 2008 measles outbreak in San Diego triggered by an unvaccinated boy infected during a visit to Switzerland exposed 893 people... . Controlling the outbreak ... cost the community close to $900,000.[37] A similar case that year in Tucson, Arizona, infected 14 people ... with measles. The outbreak cost two hospitals nearly $800,000, and tens of thousands more were spent by the state and local health departments to track down the cases, quarantine and treat the sick cases, and notify the thousands of people who might have been exposed."[38] Ropeik concluded, "society has the right and responsibility to establish laws, regulations, and choice frameworks that discourage vaccine refusal. ... [V]accine refusal costs society billions of dollars, both in direct health care costs and indirectly in lost productivity and public health spending to curtail disease outbreaks. ... [I]n many communities, vaccination rates, particularly for children, have dropped below thresholds necessary to maintain herd immunity. ... A study in the United States found that in places where it is harder to opt out, fewer people do.[36]

Becchetti and Salustri modeled disease progression in Italy with partial vaccination and concluded that herd immunity could not be reached with the prevailing rates of noncompliance with vaccines without vaccinating people under 16 years of age, though the stress on the existing hospital system could be substantially reduced.[39]

A relatively simple solution to the problem of people refusing to get vaccinated might be to require the following:

1. Everyone should purchase liability insurance for spreading contagious diseases to cover the losses from anyone who catches a contagious disease directly or indirectly from them.
1.1. A simple formula might be to reduce the premium by a factor of (1-effectiveness) of a vaccine for those who are vaccinated. For example, the premium for a vaccine that is 95 percent effective should be 5 percent of the premium for someone who is not vaccinated. Similarly, the premium for a vaccine that is only 50 percent effective should be half that of the premium for someone who is not vaccinated. The premiums for both vaccinated and unvaccinated might be set to cover the cost of the burden of diseases covered including the cost of administering liability insurance for diseases acknowledge to be contagious.
1.2. The insurance premium may also consider each individual's behavior patterns. For example, people may not have to buy the insurance unless they will be traveling to a place where the covered contagious disease may be more prevalent than it is where they currently reside and otherwise travel.
1.3. For a disease that might plausibly be eradicated, some of the insurance premiums might be used to pay for a standard ring vaccination program as well as (a) research to facilitate understanding vaccine hesitancy, (b) appropriate action to challenge the official behaviors that contributed to the vaccination hesitancy like the fake hepatitis B immunization campaign that the US CIA used to confirm the residence of Osama bin Laden prior to killing him,[40][41] and (c) public health campaign to make it easier to overcome vaccine hesitancy. After an eradication program has been declared successful, the insurance premium for that disease should drop to zero.
1.4. This is similar to the liability insurance required to drive a car in many if not all countries in the world today. That insurance rate is higher for people in higher risk groups.
2. Anyone with symptoms that could be due to a contagious disease should be legally required to consult a health care professional and enter quarantine if told to do so. The cost of the medical consultation, therapy and quarantine should be paid from the liability insurance for contagious diseases. This would include paying people for actual loss of income in quarantine by some formula that would be capped at some modest multiple of a prevailing minimum wage.

Requiring anyone with symptoms of a potentially contagious condition to seek medical attention and act according to the medical advice should reduce the transmission of disease by itself, thereby reducing the vaccination rate required to achieve herd immunity. It could also facilitate any eradication program.

Insurance payments for such a system could be based on actuarial calculations considering the evidence from research into which diseases are contagious. Contact tracing could identify several individuals as most likely for the outbreak and could estimate the proportion of the total burden of the outbreak that was most likely due to each individual using Bayesian inference. If more than one insurance carrier was involved, these estimated proportions could be used to allocate the total burden to the different insurance companies with no need to declare any one person as most likely responsible for the outbreak.

If you are fully vaccinated, you may get the insurance for free, paid by increasing the rates on others who are not vaccinated. If you have a condition for which certain vaccines are contra-indicated, e.g., egg allergies for vaccines produced using eggs, you may still get the insurance for free, with two stipulations: (i) Your condition is certified by a licensed medical practitioner as prescribed by law, and (ii) you comply fully with other regulations to minimize the communication of any disease you might catch, e.g., wearing an N95 or even an N99 mask in public and wearing disposable rubber gloves, which may also be provided to you for free in appropriate quantities with instructions on proper use. If you are caught not complying fully with appropriate public health measures, you can be required to pay the insurance plus a fine for noncompliance.

An insurance mandate of this nature could be introduced using a "fee and dividend" system that is revenue neutral or slightly beneficial for the poor and middle class, similar to carbon fee and dividend systems designed to increase the market prices for fossil fuels in a way that does not generate massive protests as happened in the UK, Mexico, France, Zimbabwe, Haiti, and elsewhere.[42]

The main purpose of requiring liability insurance for contagious diseases is not to pay for the outbreaks but to help the public understand the following:

  • Everyone benefits from others being vaccinated (and from others using other anti-rivalrous goods that can help control contagious diseases).
  • You personally could become infected, be asymptomatic, and still be responsible for close family and associates getting sick and dying.
  • Vaccines are never perfect.

This is similar to the malfunctioning forehead fever thermometer mentioned earlier: Part of the value (and in that case the only value) is to help people understand the potential impact of their actions on others.

Vaccine cartel[edit | edit source]

Two-thirds of the epidemiologists surveyed in March 2021 thought that we had “a year or less before the virus mutates to the extent that the majority of first-generation vaccines are rendered ineffective and new or modified vaccines are required.”[43] The mutation rate is proportional to the number of people who get the disease.[44]

No vaccine is 100 percent effective. The effectiveness of the Pfizer and Moderna vaccines have been estimated at 90 percent. That means that in a group with some people vaccinated and some not, if 20 percent of unvaccinated people got sick, roughly 2 percent of the vaccinated got sick.[45]

As strains develop that are resistant to a vaccine, they will increasingly threaten people who have been vaccinated. Thus, any limits on the production of vaccines increase the risks to everyone, even those already vaccinated. In particular, when distribution is limited by demands for patent royalties, it threatens the health of all. It's "penny wise and pound foolish" and will almost certainly lead to more deaths among those already vaccinated. The disease burden among people in the developed world could cost more than if they had paid reasonable patent royalties for the entire world and otherwise worked to increase the speed of distribution of the vaccines.

In this regard, it's good that the Biden administration announced May 5, 2021, that they would support "waiving intellectual property protections for coronavirus vaccines ... . The United States had been a major holdout at the World Trade Organization over a proposal to suspend some of the world economic body’s intellectual property protections, which could allow drugmakers across the globe access to the closely guarded trade secrets of how the viable vaccines have been made." Biden had previously been criticized for failing to support waiving patent royalties for coronavirus vaccines.[46]

A couple of months earlier the Health Global Access Project (Health GAP) said that, "Expanding Vaccine Manufacturing Capacity Solely Within the Pharma Cartel is a Recipe for Perpetual Vaccine Apartheid and Artificial Scarcity". In an “unusual pact between fierce rivals”, J&J "will give Merck $268.8 million in U.S. taxpayer funding to use its capacity to manufacture J&J’s vaccine. ... Every country in the world is up in arms about inadequate supplies of COVID-19 vaccines. Rich countries had tried to ensure against delayed vaccinations by advance purchases ... . For the rest of the world, including 130 countries that as of last week had received no vaccines, artificially limited supplies means waiting in line for years, more deaths, more social and economic disruption, and development of more contagious and vaccine-resistant variants. It’s a recipe for a never-ending pandemic. The solution to the false supply scarcity should have been advance planning and early agreement to override patent protections ... . Instead vaccine monopolists schemed to maintain rigid control over supply, price, and distribution, both to increase profits and prioritize their monopolies at the risk of public health."[47]

The vast majority of the costs associated with many patented products is in the research; the unit costs of production are often a very small part of the cost and can be made even smaller as the cumulative production increases. This increases the importance of considering having taxpayers pay any patent royalties for anti-rivalrous products and not requiring the end user to think about whether they should pay the higher cost.[48]

Cost and benefit[edit | edit source]

How much should countries spend on health? A 2003 discussion paper by William Savedoff for the World Health Organization notes that, "The range in per capita health spending across countries is larger than 100 to 1, and this translates into spending of anywhere between 1 percent to well over 10 percent of national income." Five percent of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is mentioned as an unofficial target that has been used in some international comparisons and evaluations but was never officially approved. Savedoff mentioned a 1988 WHO resolution that does not mention 5 percent but does recommend taking action 'to reallocate existing resources more effectively, "reduce waste and increase efficient use of resources", etc.'[49]

To the extent that the discussion with Figures 1 and 2 above is accurate, an important contributor to advances in public health is a free press with a substantive firewall between people with power and the editorial policies of the media, preferably with substantive citizen-directed subsidies for journalism. Subsidies like this were provided in early US history by the Postal Service Act of 1792, which was funded at roughly 0.2 percent of GDP. However, in the latter half of the nineteenth century, advertising gradually grew to represent roughly 10 times that to 2 percent of GDP, where it has been since the early twentieth century, swamping the postal subsidies.

With adequate limits on political corruption and malfeasance in government, it may then be worth reviewing the most recent Global Burden of Disease Study published by the World Health Organization (WHO).[50] This methodology has been developed since 1990 to help guide public health investments in areas of greatest long-term need. In such studies, disease burden is often expressed in terms of Disability-adjusted life years (DALYs).[51] DALYs can be expressed in US dollars (at Purchasing power parity, PPP) or any other currency by multiplying DALY components by the average annual income (Gross Domestic Product, GDP, per capita). However, investments even by poor countries should not be limited to selecting from currently existing options but should also consider investing in research to find lower cost and / or more effective approaches to these problems. Might we find other examples like the eradication of smallpox that could show massive returns on investments that are miniscule compared with the burden of disease? One example mentioned above might be improved diagnosis of sexually transmitted infections (STIs). Others might include health promotion and research to identify cost effective changes in health care for pregnant women and child care that could pay for themselves with a respectable interest after the children enter the workforce: Natural experiments in the US have documented a handsome return on investment from such interventions in terms of the increased taxes paid on increase income accompanied by reductions in the cost of health care and the crime rate.[52]

Policy implications[edit | edit source]

Knowledge is anti-rivarous, especially regarding how things work and how the public could get more from less. In particular, the following summarizes some of the most important implications of the discussion in this article:

  1. Citizen-directed subsidies for journalism could reduce political corruption and increase the rate of progress against many if not all of the problems facing humanity today. A reasonable target might be 2 percent of Gross Domestic Product (GDP), which is roughly what the US spent on advertising in the twentieth century and which overwhelmed the 0.2 percent of GDP devoted to newspaper subsidies under the US Postal Service Act of 1792. Two percent is also roughly what the US spends on accounting, including creative accounting, such as what contributed to infamous financial disasters such as the savings and loan crisis of the 1980s and 1990s and the Enron scandal of 2001.[53] Two percent is also the average annual increase in productivity (GDP per capita adjusted for inflation) in the US between 1947 and 2019: We could pay for such citizen-directed subsidies from the increase on productivity from one year. More importantly, if the increased exposure of political corruption increases the rate of economic growth, which seems likely, these citizen-directed subsidies would soon become free, paid for from income we would not have without them.
  2. Future articles in refereed scientific journals should never be behind a paywall, because none of the research described in those articles is funded from copyrights, which means that paywalls are an obstacle to "the Progress of Science and useful Arts", which is the purpose of the Copyright Clause in the US Constitution.
  3. To the extent that the international pharmaceutical industry operates a vaccine cartel as suggested above,[47] it should be broken using antitrust law.
  4. Other experiments should be conducted in funding research in ways that prohibit patenting the results and require all results of such publicly funded research to be placed in the public domain -- but only after adequate funding is provided for investigative journalism to limit wasting such research funding, as indicated above.[54]
  5. Everyone should be required to purchase liability insurance for spreading contagious diseases with the rates adjusted based on their vaccination history, general health, location, and travel.

Mathematical appendix[edit | edit source]

We consider the following in pricing:

  1. P = Price to the consumer.
  2. = Volume of consumption at unit price P. V could be zero for sufficiently large P and could be unbounded for sufficiently negative P, i.e., when people are paid to consume the good. We expect to be monotonically non-increasing in P.
  3. = The total (gross) benefits that others derive from consumption of one additional unit at consumption volume V. This could be zero when V is 0. We expect to increase to a maximum then decline as additional consumption is diverted to applications that are not anti-rivalrous, e.g., with N95 face masks used to protect a person from breathing particles that are not contagious. If there is a maximum, it should be unique with the function non-decreasing prior to that maximum and non-increasing after the maximum.
  4. F = Fixed costs required to develop the product and associated production processes. This in theory could increase with V as people spend more money to develop more efficient production processes justified by large volumes of demand, but we will suppress those effects in this notation to simplify the discussion.
  5. = The marginal cost of producing and distributing an additional unit at volume V.
  6. = total cost to society at production volume V and price P.

We want to select P to minimize T. Equivalently, this would maximize the net benefits to others after subtracting fixed and total variable costs.

In many practical applications, it will be clear without a major empirical modelling effort that the benefits to society from someone consuming one additional unit, B, substantially exceeds the marginal cost of producing and distributing that unit, M. In such cases, the optimal price to the consumer, P, will be 0. This will not be true for goods like N95 respirators, which have uses that are not anti-rivalrous. For such products, it may be desirable to invest in more careful efforts to model B and M.

See also[edit | edit source]

References[edit | edit source]

Notes[edit | edit source]

  1. For a similar article discussing externalities and infectious diseases but not news, see Spencer Graves; Douglas A. Samuelson (March 2022). "Externalities, public goods, and infectious diseases". Real-world economics review (99): 25-56. Wikidata Q111367750. ISSN 1755-9472. http://www.paecon.net/PAEReview/issue99/whole99.pdf. 
  2. 2.0 2.1 2.2 Jane Seymour, Eradicating Smallpox (PDF), Center for Global Development, Wikidata Q99372019.
  3. 3.0 3.1 3.2 Guy Rolnik; Julia Cagé; Joshua Gans; Ellen P. Goodman; Brian G. Knight; Andrea Prat; Anya Schiffrin (1 July 2019), Protecting Journalism in the Age of Digital Platforms (PDF), Booth School of Business, Wikidata Q106465358, pp. 3, 14, 28, 36, 48.
  4. Garrett (2000, p. 11).
  5. Garrett (2000, p. 10).
  6. Steven Pinker (13 June 2021). "How Humans Gained an ‘Extra Life’". The New York Times. Wikidata Q107221672. ISSN 0362-4331. https://www.nytimes.com/2021/05/11/books/review/extra-life-steven-johnson.html. . Steven Johnson (11 May 2021). Extra Life: A short history of living longer (in en). Riverhead Books. Wikidata Q107221328. ISBN 978-0-525-53885-1. . See also Steven Johnson (27 April 2021). "How Humanity Gave Itself an Extra Life". The New York Times. Wikidata Q107221825. ISSN 0362-4331. https://www.nytimes.com/2021/04/27/magazine/global-life-span.html. .
  7. Lawrence Lessig (18 August 2005). "Do You Floss?". London Review of Books 27 (16). Wikidata Q104836676. ISSN 0260-9592. https://web.archive.org/web/20061210095140/http://www.lrb.co.uk/v27/n16/less01_.html. .
  8. Pekka Nikander; Ville Eloranta; Kimmo Karhu; Kari Hiekkanen (2 June 2020), Digitalisation, anti-rival compensation and governance: Need for experiments, Wikidata Q106510738.
  9. Graves (2014).
  10. Mark Cooper (July 2018). "Governing the global climate commons: The political economy of state and local action, after the U.S. flip-flop on the Paris Agreement". Energy Policy 118: 440-454. doi:10.1016/J.ENPOL.2018.03.037. Wikidata Q63090519. ISSN 0301-4215. .
  11. Costanza et al. studied a list of known externalities and estimated that, "Ecoservices contribute more than twice as much to human well-being as" the gross world product. Unfortunately, uncertainties in their estimates are huge, and the real magnitude of the externalities they studied may only be a fifth of that. However, they noted that they had considered only a portion of known externalities, and the real numbers could easily be twice as large. This could mean that if all the externalities were properly considered, the real economy could easily be five times as large as documented in the gross world product. Austin explained how this means that the world's economic and political leaders are being pushed to do things that are massively counterproductive, driving climate change into a major crisis because the worlds leading economists are focusing on the wrong things, pretending externalities are negligible, when the global expert consensus is that these externalities will ultimately prove to be catastrophic. He suggests that we need serious Pigovian taxes on the most important externalities, especially those driving global warming. see Robert Costanza; Rudolf de Groot; Paul Sutton; Sander van der Ploeg; Sharolyn J. Anderson; Ida Kubiszewski; Stephen Farber; R. Kerry Turner (May 2014). "Changes in the global value of ecosystem services". Global Environmental Change 26: 152-158. doi:10.1016/J.GLOENVCHA.2014.04.002. Wikidata Q29391230. ISSN 0959-3780. , and Duncan Austin (2021). "Pigou and the dropped stitch of economics". Real-world economics review (95): 71-86. Wikidata Q107120300. ISSN 1755-9472. http://www.paecon.net/PAEReview/issue95/whole95.pdf. .
  12. An extreme negative example was supplied by Jamal Khashoggi, who was reportedly murdered on orders from someone who did not want disseminated information they believed Khashoggi seemed likely to expose. If that information had already been widely known, and the mastermind(s) of Khashoggi's murder had no reason to suspect that he might disseminate other damaging information, he would not have to do anything to continue living, making such news anti-rivalrous, even if there were no action to limit said corruption, and therefore no positive externalities.
  13. See Robert W. McChesney; John Nichols (2016). People get ready: The fight against a jobless economy and a citizenless democracy (in en). Bold Type Books. Wikidata Q87619174. ISBN 978-1-56858-521-5. . and other references cited in "Confirmation bias and conflict" and "The Great American Paradox".
  14. An alternative explanation may be the claim that the US has greater cultural diversity leading to mistreatment of Native Americans and African Americans in the US, the latter being documented by McGhee (2021). By contrast, the claim in this article is that racism in the US may to a large extent be a product of differences media funding. The reliance on advertising for the vast majority of the money for the media means that any media executive in the US must be more careful than in the other 14 countries surveyed by Benson and Powers (2011) about disseminating information that might offend business and political leaders. Differences in the resulting media culture may be responsible for both the slow progress in public health apparent in Figures 1 and 2 and some substantial portion of the magnitude of problems with race relations in the US. Heather McGhee (2021). The Sum of Us: What racism costs us and how we can prosper together (in en). Random House. Wikidata Q105635869. ISBN 978-0-525-50957-8. .
  15. Borden (1942, Table 1, p. 48) claimed that total advertising in the US in 1865 was $7.8 million or $0.22 per capita, which translate into 0.08 percent of nominal GDP. Galbi is skeptical of that number, but it was probably less than the roughly 2 percent of GDP that advertising represented from 1900 to 2007 per Douglas Aziz Galbi (14 September 2008), U.S. advertising expenditure data, Wikidata Q107143246. The 1865 numbers are in Neil H. Borden (1942), The Economic Effects of Advertising, Richard D. Irwin, Inc., Wikidata Q107083905.
  16. Penny Abernathy (2020), News Deserts and Ghost Newspapers: Will local news survive?, University of North Carolina Press, Wikidata Q100251717.
  17. E.g., Glenn Kessler (1 December 2016). "Justin Trudeau’s claim that Castro made ‘significant improvements’ to Cuban health care and education". The Washington Post. Wikidata Q106337240. ISSN 0190-8286. https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/fact-checker/wp/2016/12/01/justin-trudeaus-claim-that-castro-made-significant-improvements-to-cuban-health-care-and-education/. ; see also the general review in w:Healthcare in Cuba. The data plotted in Figures 1 and 2 came from the United Nations. The World Factbook, published by the Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) of the United States government, gives numbers that are similar but different. Given the record of hostility of the US government toward Cuba since the Cuban Revolution of 1959, we would expect the CIA data to reflect any credible claims of problems with data available elsewhere.
  18. Patents and copyrights may have made good sense prior to the US Civil War when US federal government spending averaged roughly 2 percent percent of Gross Domestic Product (GDP). However, there is substantial literature today insisting that patents, in particular, do not "promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts", as required in the US by the Copyright Clause in the Constitution, but rather do the opposite. This is particularly true of Strategic lawsuits against public participation, as described by Lawrence Lessig in his book, Free Culture: He claims that MP3.com and Napster were shut down, not because they were violating copyright law, but because they could not afford the legal fees required to defend their rights to do what they were doing. He does not mention that few if any scholars get a penny in copyright royalties for publications in refereed academic journals, though this is the case. He also does not mention the issue of anti-rivalry, apart from noting that language, free and open-source software (FOSS), and perhaps data in some cases are anti-rivalrous, as noted above. See also Unrigging the media and the economy.
  19. Sophie Ochmann; Max Roser (2018). "Smallpox". Our World in Data. Wikidata Q106328190. https://ourworldindata.org/smallpox. .
  20. Fangjun Zhou; Jeanne Santoli; Mark L. Messonnier; Hussain R. Yusuf; Abigail Shefer; Susan Y. Chu; Lance Rodewald; Rafael Harpaz (1 December 2005). "Economic Evaluation of the 7-Vaccine Routine Childhood Immunization Schedule in the United States, 2001". JAMA Pediatrics 159 (12): 1136. doi:10.1001/ARCHPEDI.159.12.1136. Wikidata Q29543836. ISSN 1072-4710. PMID 16330737. http://archpedi.jamanetwork.com/article.aspx?articleid=486191. .
  21. Louis Johnston; Samuel H. Williamson, What Was the U.S. GDP Then?, MeasuringWorth, Wikidata Q56881105.
  22. Declan Walsh (14 February 2007). "Polio cases jump in Pakistan as clerics declare vaccination an American plot". The Guardian. Wikidata Q107001525. ISSN 0261-3077. https://www.theguardian.com/world/2007/feb/15/pakistan.topstories3. . In 2011 the Central Intelligence Agency of the US government (CIA) reportedly conducted a fake hepatitis B immunization campaign to collect blood samples from Osama bin Laden's Abbottabad compound to confirm the genetic identity of children living there before staging the attack during which he, two sons, a daughter-in-law, and a guest were killed. Heidi Larson (27 May 2012). "The CIA's fake vaccination drive has damaged the battle against polio". The Guardian. Wikidata Q107001281. ISSN 0261-3077. https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2012/may/27/cia-fake-vaccination-polio. . "Bin Laden death: 'CIA doctor' accused of treason". BBC News Online. 6 October 2011. Wikidata Q107001363. https://www.bbc.com/news/world-south-asia-15206639. 
  23. Isaac Ghinai; Chris Willott; Ibrahim Dadari; Heidi J Larson (3 December 2013). "Listening to the rumours: what the northern Nigeria polio vaccine boycott can tell us ten years on.". Global Public Health 8 (10): 1138-1150. doi:10.1080/17441692.2013.859720. Wikidata Q33901420. ISSN 1744-1692. PMID 24294986. PMC 4098042. //www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC4098042/. .
  24. Ian Njeru; Yusuf Ajack; Charles Muitherero et al. (7 June 2016). "Did the call for boycott by the Catholic bishops affect the polio vaccination coverage in Kenya in 2015? A cross-sectional study". The Pan African medical journal 24: 120. doi:10.11604/PAMJ.2016.24.120.8986. Wikidata Q37235100. ISSN 1937-8688. PMID 27642458. PMC 5012825. //www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC5012825/. .
  25. The use of a malfunctioning forehead fever thermometer can be anti-rivalrous if its use convinces people who are not feeling well to avoid an enclosed space where they might infect someone else.
  26. George M. Whitesides (10 August 2009), Zero cost diagnostics, Wikidata Q107005686. See also Peter Diamandis; Steven Kotler (21 February 2012). Abundance: The Future Is Better Than You Think (in en). Free Press. Wikidata Q4670623. ISBN 978-1-4516-1421-3. OCLC 741542469. , pp. 194-196.
  27. Jon Gertner (25 March 2021). "Unlocking the Covid Code". The New York Times. Wikidata Q106354534. ISSN 0362-4331. https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2021/03/25/magazine/genome-sequencing-covid-variants.html. .
  28. Jennifer Kahn (3 June 2021). "The Disease Detective". The New York Times. Wikidata Q107125305. ISSN 0362-4331. https://www.nytimes.com/2021/06/03/magazine/metagenomic-sequencing.html. .
  29. Yao-Tsun Li; Martin Linster; Ian H Mendenhall; Yvonne C F Su; Gavin J D Smith (1 December 2019). "Avian influenza viruses in humans: lessons from past outbreaks". British Medical Bulletin 132 (1): 81-95. doi:10.1093/BMB/LDZ036. Wikidata Q92060802. ISSN 0007-1420. PMID 31848585. PMC 6992886. //www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC6992886/. . Also, Udayan Joseph; Yvonne C F Su; Dhanasekaran Vijaykrishna; Gavin J D Smith (18 July 2016). "The ecology and adaptive evolution of influenza A interspecies transmission". Influenza and Other Respiratory Viruses 11 (1): 74-84. doi:10.1111/IRV.12412. Wikidata Q30390642. ISSN 1750-2640. PMID 27426214. PMC 5155642. //www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC5155642/. .
  30. The figure of 16 percent was computed by dividing 1.146 billion people with sexually transmitted infections excluding HIV by 7.38 billion to get 0.155, approximately 16 percent. The 1.146 billion is from GBD 2015 Disease and Injury Incidence and Prevalence Collaborators et al. (1 October 2016). "Global, regional, and national incidence, prevalence, and years lived with disability for 310 diseases and injuries, 1990-2015: a systematic analysis for the Global Burden of Disease Study 2015". The Lancet 388 (10053): 1545-1602. doi:10.1016/S0140-6736(16)31678-6. Wikidata Q27468570. ISSN 0140-6736. PMID 27733282. PMC 5055577. https://www.thelancet.com/journals/lancet/article/PIIS0140-6736(16)31678-6/fulltext#%20. .
  31. The four sexually transmitted infections monitored in the study were human papillomavirus (HPV), chlamydia, genital herpes and trichomoniasis. Almost half of the African Americans in the study were infected. Lawrence K. Altman (12 March 2008). "Sex Infections Found in Quarter of Teenage Girls". The New York Times. Wikidata Q107003440. ISSN 0362-4331. https://www.nytimes.com/2008/03/12/science/12std.html. .
  32. Nicholas Confessore (6 May 2021). "Michael Lewis Chronicles the Story of Covid’s Cassandras". The New York Times. Wikidata Q107006303. ISSN 0362-4331. https://www.nytimes.com/2021/05/06/books/review/the-premonition-michael-lewis.html. .
  33. Daniel E. O'Leary; Veda C. Storey (28 September 2020). "A Google–Wikipedia–Twitter Model as a Leading Indicator of the Numbers of Coronavirus Deaths". Intelligent Systems in Accounting, Finance and Management 27 (3): 151-158. Wikidata Q107006170. ISSN 1550-1949. https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC7646638/. .
  34. Alyssa Danigelis (2 December 2020). "Why the New National Wastewater Surveillance System Matters". IDEXX Currents. Wikidata Q107010775. https://www.idexxcurrents.com/en/latest/why-the-new-national-wastewater-surveillance-system-matters/. .
  35. National Wastewater Surveillance System, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Wikidata Q107011136.
  36. 36.0 36.1 David Ropeik (6 June 2013). "How society should respond to the risk of vaccine rejection". Human Vaccines & Immunotherapeutics 9 (8): 1815-1818. doi:10.4161/HV.25250. Wikidata Q34354032. ISSN 2164-5515. PMID 23807359. PMC 3906287. https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC3906287/. . See also "Vaccine hesitancy" and Saad B Omer; Kyle S Enger; Lawrence H. Moulton; Neal A Halsey; Shannon Stokley; Daniel A Salmon (15 October 2008). "Geographic clustering of nonmedical exemptions to school immunization requirements and associations with geographic clustering of pertussis". American Journal of Epidemiology 168 (12): 1389-1396. doi:10.1093/AJE/KWN263. Wikidata Q57954062. ISSN 0002-9262. PMID 18922998. http://aje.oxfordjournals.org/content/168/12/1389.full. .
  37. David E Sugerman; Albert E Barskey; Maryann G Delea et al. (22 March 2010). "Measles outbreak in a highly vaccinated population, San Diego, 2008: role of the intentionally undervaccinated". Pediatrics 125 (4): 747-755. doi:10.1542/PEDS.2009-1653. Wikidata Q34105917. ISSN 0031-4005. PMID 20308208. .
  38. Sanny Y Chen; Shoana Anderson; Preeta K Kutty et al. (28 April 2011). "Health care-associated measles outbreak in the United States after an importation: challenges and economic impact". Journal of Infectious Diseases 203 (11): 1517-1525. doi:10.1093/INFDIS/JIR115. Wikidata Q37870581. ISSN 0022-1899. PMID 21531693. .
  39. Leonardo Becchetti; Francesco Salustri (12 January 2021), Optimal Policies for Vaccine Campaign: The Case of COVID-19, Social Science Research Network, Wikidata Q107065780.
  40. Larson H (27 May 2012). "The CIA's fake vaccination drive has damaged the battle against polio". The Guardian. Archived from the original on 11 July 2020. Retrieved 3 June 2012.
  41. "Bin Laden death: 'CIA doctor' accused of treason". BBC News Online. 6 October 2011. Archived from the original on 11 July 2020. Retrieved 8 October 2011.
  42. e.g., Nigeria.
  43. Holly Ellyatt (30 March 2021). "Mutations could render current Covid vaccines ineffective in a year or less, epidemiologists warn". CNBC. Wikidata Q107013936. https://www.cnbc.com/2021/03/30/mutations-could-make-current-covid-vaccines-ineffective-soon-survey.html. .
  44. In living organisms, the error rates in copying DNA have been estimated at between 10-4 and 10-5 per base or "letter" in the DNA sequence. See Ron Milo; Rob B. Phillips, What is the error rate in transcription and translation?, Wikidata Q106357717. However, many living organisms have mechanisms for finding and fixing errors. And many of the errors that don't get corrected also can't function. Of those that continue to function, only a few are more transmissible or more virulent (with either a higher risk of death or long-term disability). For COVID-19, we first note that 129 million cases with 2.8 million deaths had been reported worldwide by 2021-04-02 per COVID-19 Dashboard by the Center for Systems Science and Engineering (CSSE) at Johns Hopkins University (JHU), Wikidata Q106357967. See also w:COVID-19 pandemic by country and territory. With a world population of 7.8 billion people, this is a reported case rate of just under 17,000 per million population. On that same date (2021-04-02) the Wikipedia article on "Variants of SARS-CoV-2" listed 10 "notable variants", some of which are more transmissible and more virulent than the original strain. If the number of people infected had been dramatically reduced though more effective interventions like contact tracing, masking, and targeted quarantining, the transmissibility and virulency of the worst strains would likely also have been substantively reduced along with the threat that current vaccines could be rendered ineffective. Cell phone data could be used for contact tracing, but this may require enabling legislation in some countries.
  45. 0.02 = 0.2(1-.9). Mark G. Thompson; Jefferey L Burgess; Allison L. Naleway et al. (2 April 2021). "Interim Estimates of Vaccine Effectiveness of BNT162b2 and mRNA-1273 COVID-19 Vaccines in Preventing SARS-CoV-2 Infection Among Health Care Personnel, First Responders, and Other Essential and Frontline Workers — Eight U.S. Locations". Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report 70 (13): 495–500. Wikidata Q107063587. ISSN 0149-2195. https://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/volumes/70/wr/mm7013e3.htm. . See also "vaccine efficacy".
  46. Thomas Kaplan; Sheryl Gay Stolberg; Rebecca Robbins (5 May 2021). "Taking ‘Extraordinary Measures,’ Biden Backs Suspending Patents on Vaccines". The New York Times. Wikidata Q107014196. ISSN 0362-4331. https://www.nytimes.com/2021/05/05/us/politics/biden-covid-vaccine-patents.html. .
  47. 47.0 47.1 Brook Baker (3 March 2021). "Expanding Vaccine Manufacturing Capacity Solely Within the Pharma Cartel is a Recipe for Perpetual Vaccine Apartheid and Artificial Scarcity". Health Global Access Project. Wikidata Q107014783. https://healthgap.org/expanding-vaccine-manufacturing-capacity-solely-within-the-pharma-cartel-is-a-recipe-for-perpetual-vaccine-apartheid-and-artificial-scarcity/. .
  48. Baker (2016) further suggests that this implies that the development of such products should be funded directly by taxpayers with the results placed in the public domain. See also Unrigging the media and the economy.
  49. William Savedoff (2003), How Much Should Countries Spend on Health? (PDF), Wikidata Q107034910.
  50. The Lancet: Latest global disease estimates reveal perfect storm of rising chronic diseases and public health failures fuelling COVID-19 pandemic, University of Washington Institute for Health Metrics and Evaluation, 15 October 2020, Wikidata Q107062102.
  51. The World Health Organization (WHO) used age weighting and time discounting at 3 percent in DALYs prior to 2010 but discontinued using them starting in 2010. See: Colin Mathers; Gretchen Stevens (November 2013), WHO methods and data sources for global burden of disease estimates 2000-2011 (PDF), World Health Organization, Wikidata Q107023735
  52. Nathaniel Hendren; Ben Sprung-Keyser (1 February 2020). "A Unified Welfare Analysis of Government Policies". Quarterly Journal of Economics 135 (3): 1209-1318. Wikidata Q107036253. ISSN 0033-5533. https://scholar.harvard.edu/hendren/publications/unified-welfare-analysis-government-policies. . Summarized in Seema Jayachandran (10 July 2020). "Social Programs Can Sometimes Turn a Profit for Taxpayers". The New York Times. Wikidata Q107036210. ISSN 0362-4331. https://www.nytimes.com/2020/07/10/business/social-programs-profit.html. .
  53. William K. Black (2005), The Best Way to Rob a Bank is to Own One, University of Texas Press, Wikidata Q16428866
  54. Baker (2016, pp. 80-81) noted that, "The Bayh-Dole Act of 1980 allowed for universities, research institutions, private companies, and individuals operating on government contracts to gain control of patents derived from their work, thereby creating the opportunity for universities to earn large rents from patents and for researchers to form their own companies, all relying on knowledge and expertise obtained on government contracts." He notes further that the vast majority of the cost for vaccines, drugs, and diagnostic procedures in the US are for patent royalties, enforced the world over through the World Trade Organization. The unit cost is almost negligible by comparison. The fact that the costs of health care are greater in the US than in other advanced countries raises questions about whether the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980 has benefitted the taxpayers or has had the opposite effect.
  55. See also Unrigging the media and the economy.