Jump to content

Karl Marx/Capital1/Part2

From Wikiversity

This is a resource about the second part of the first volume of Capital by Karl Marx, entitled "The Transformation of Money into Capital".

This part holds three chapters:

  • Chapter 4: The General Formula for Capital
  • Chapter 5: Contradictions in the General Formula
  • Chapter 6: The Sale and Purchase of Labour-Power

This part follows the first part of the first volume of Capital, in which Marx treated Commodities, Exchange and Money. The book started with a model of exchange based on barter of commodities. It is important to note, that at the time when Marx wrote his work, anyone was familiar with the (Ricardian) labour theory of value. Marx does not spend many words proving its correctness. So he simply assumes that exchange is based on the socially necessary labour time. Marx moves from this C-C relation to the form of exchange, mediated by money, C-M-C. Finally the M-C-M circulation is explained: money becoming the aim and object of exchange.

It is easy to understand that M-C-M only makes sense if it results in an increment of value: M-C-(M+ΔM).[1] The increment of value is called surplus-value, and the problem is of course, where surplus-value comes from, if the M-C and C-M transactions are exchanges of equivalents. Only if a commodity can be found, that has the capacity to produce more value than it itself has, the mystery can be unveiled. "This is the broad transitional story told in these three chapters. The focus begins to shift from commodity exchange to capital circulation."[2]

Chapter 4: The General Formula for Capital

[edit | edit source]

In this chapter the logical analysis of commodity circulation is intertwined with historic development: "World trade and the world market date from the sixteenth century, and from then on the modern history of capital starts to unfold." (p. 247)[3] In the transition from feudalism to capitalism merchants' capital and usurers' capital played important historical roles. These forms of capital must be distinguished from industrial capital, that is considered the central form of capital in (industrial) capitalism. But it is the independent social power of money, and of the money holders, that is necessary to come to a definition of capital. As long as the money only works as a circulating medium, the exchange cycle is completed with C-M-C: selling in order to buy. But if we consider the opposite movement: M-C-M, buying in order to sell, we see that money can transform into capital. In the simple circulation of commodities the cycle M-C-M "appears to lack any content, because it is tautological" (p. 250-251). The cycle M-C-M can only be considered as a meaningful process on its own, if it leads to a quantitative change: M-C-(M+ΔM). The original sum advanced to buy commodities returns after the selling of the commodities as "the original sum advanced plus an increment. This increment or excess over the original value I call 'surplus-value'. The value originally advanced, therefore, not only remains intact while in circulation, but increases its magnitude, adds to itself a surplus-value, or is valorized [verwertet sich]. And this movement converts it into capital. (p. 251-251).[4]

As Harvey says: we now arrive for the first time at "the concept of surplus-value, which is, of course, fundamental to all of Marx's analysis. (…) Here, finally, is the definition of "capital"." He emphasizes that capital is not conceived as a thing, but as a process-"a process, specifically, of the circulation of values".[5] He stresses the importance of this process definition of capital: a radical departure from the definition in classical political economy, "where capital was traditionally understood as a stock of assets."[6] The process definition of capital is made explicit by Marx:

To which paragraph Harvey adds, for good measure, that this sentence is meant ironically, of course, and that the occult qualities of capital and its seemingly magical capacity to lay golden eggs "exist only in the realm of appearance".[7]

Chapter 5: Contradictions in the General Formula

[edit | edit source]

Chapter 6: The Sale and Purchase of Labour-Power

[edit | edit source]

References

[edit | edit source]
  1. Δ, pronounce "delta" is an increase (in value).
  2. Harvey 2010, p. 86.
  3. References to page numbers will be made to the 1990 edition, translated by Ben Fowkes, and published by Penguin Books (which is the same as the 1976 edition of New Left Review.
  4. Along with the concept of surplus-value, the concept of Verwertung is introduced here. In the translation by Fowkes (and on the English language Wikipedia "valorization" is used (see footnote at p. 252). With Verwertung Marx refers to both the process in which a capital is bestowed into commodities, and to the increase of value in the process. In the next chapter a complete paragraph is devoted to this issue. Here Marx will call "Kapital (…) sich selbst verwertender Wert" (capital, value which can perform its own valorization process.") (p. 302)
  5. Harvey 2010, p. 88.
  6. Harvey 2010, p. 88; Harvey also mentions the fundamental difference of the "process definition" from the way in which nowadays conventional economics defines capital as a thing-like "factor of production" and he suggests a connection with the so-called "capital controversy" where it was shown that "the whole of contemporary economic theory is dangerously close to being founded on a tautology: the monetary value of K in physical asset-form is determined by what it is supposed to explain, viz. the value of the commodities produced." (Harvey 2010, p. 89)
  7. Harvey 2010, p. 90.

Sources

[edit | edit source]
  • Harvey, David (2010). A Companion to Marx's Capital. London / New York: Verso. ISBN 978 1 84467 359 9.